Cookies help us run our site more efficiently.

By clicking “Accept”, you agree to the storing of cookies on your device to enhance site navigation, analyze site usage, and assist in our marketing efforts. View our Privacy Policy for more information or to customize your cookie preferences.

The Constitutional Case Against Exclusionary Zoning

News Feed
Friday, June 14, 2024

America is suffering from a severe housing shortage, and one of the main culprits is exclusionary zoning: regulations that restrict the amount and type of housing that property owners are allowed to construct on their land. Exclusionary zoning slows economic growth, severely limits economic mobility, and imposes burdens that disproportionately fall on racial minorities.No one simple solution to this problem exists. But a crucial tool may lie in the Constitution: the takings clause of the Fifth Amendment. The clause requires that, when the government takes “private property,” it must pay “just compensation” (usually the fair market value of the property rights taken). As we argue in a forthcoming Texas Law Review article, because exclusionary zoning severely restricts property owners’ right to use their land, we believe that it qualifies as such a taking, and is therefore unconstitutional unless the government pays compensation. Consistent enforcement of this interpretation would severely constrain exclusionary zoning, limiting it to cases where policy makers believe the benefits are worth the costs of paying compensation—and where they have the resources to do so.Just as there is substantial cross-ideological agreement on the policy aspects of zoning reform, there can be similar broad agreement on the constitutional dimension of this issue. One of us, Ilya Somin, is a libertarian sympathetic to originalism. The other, Joshua Braver, is a progressive living constitutionalist. We differ on many things, but agree here.The most significant type of exclusionary-zoning restriction is single-family-home zoning, which restricts housing construction in an area to homes that house only one family. Some 70 percent of all land zoned for residential use in the United States is limited to single-family residences only. Other types of exclusionary-zoning restrictions in many areas include minimum lot sizes, parking mandates, height restrictions, and more.[M. Nolan Gray: Cancel zoning]Exclusionary zoning severely reduces the housing supply in many jurisdictions, thereby preventing people from moving to areas where they could find better jobs and educational opportunities. It also increases homelessness by pricing poor residents out of the housing market. Exclusionary zoning causes enormous harm.In an important recent study, the economists Gilles Duranton and Diego Puga found that abolition of zoning restrictions in seven major urban areas would increase America’s GDP by almost 8 percent. That’s because zoning blocks many people from moving to areas where they would be more productive. Even many current homeowners in severely restricted areas stand to benefit from zoning reform. They can gain from the resulting growth and innovation, and from lower housing costs for their children, among other things. For these and other reasons, curbing exclusionary zoning unites progressives, such as the members of President Joe Biden’s Council of Economic Advisers and the former Obama CEA chair Jason Furman, with libertarian-leaning free marketeers like Edward Glaeser of Harvard and Bryan Caplan of George Mason University.Exclusionary zoning also has a horrible history of racism and classism. In Buchanan v. Warley (1917), the Supreme Court ruled that explicitly zoning neighborhoods by race was unconstitutional. But as scholars such as Richard Rothstein and Jessica Trounstine have documented, many jurisdictions got around the decision by enacting facially neutral laws that effectively excluded poor minorities by making it impossible for them to afford housing in the area. Many jurisdictions similarly priced out white poor people as well.In 1926, the Supreme Court upheld such practices in Village of Euclid v. Ambler Realty Company, despite the district court’s warning that doing so would empower local governments “to classify the population and segregate them according to their income or situation in life.” Judge David C. Westenhaver of the Ohio District Court also presciently warned that the decision would result in racial segregation. Euclid was a terrible mistake, one the Supreme Court should fix.And it can do so: When the Bill of Rights was enacted, in 1791, the right of private property was generally understood to include a right not just to exclude, but also to determine the use of that property. William Blackstone, the great British jurist whose Commentaries on the Laws of England enormously influenced the founding generation, famously wrote that “the third absolute right, inherent in every Englishman, is that of property: which consists in the free use, enjoyment, and disposal of all his acquisitions” (emphasis added). Use undoubtedly included building a house on one’s own property. Blackstone’s formulation was echoed by many of the American Founders, including—most notably—James Madison, the principal author of the takings clause. At the time of the founding, like today, housing was one of the most common uses of land.Some originalists argue that the Bill of Rights, when applied to state and local governments, should be interpreted as understood not in 1791, but in 1868, when the ratification of the Fourteenth Amendment extended the limitations of the Bill of Rights to the states. In the 1868 understanding, the takings clause protected the owner’s right to use his property at his own discretion even more clearly than in 1791. In his influential 1868 treatise on constitutional law, Michigan Supreme Court Justice Thomas Cooley wrote that “any injury to the property of an individual which deprives the owner of the ordinary use of it is equivalent to a taking, and entitles him to compensation.” Prominent federal- and state-court takings decisions around the same time also emphasized the centrality of the right to use, including the Supreme Court’s famous 1871 decision in Pumpelly v. Green Bay Company. All significant forms of exclusionary zoning constrain the right to use, and therefore at least presumptively violate the takings clause.Not every restriction on an owner’s right to use qualifies as a taking under the original meaning. Regulations that fit within the so-called police-power exception were not considered takings. Although the police-power exception has never been precisely defined, it generally applies to regulations that protect against significant threats to health and safety, such as fire, flooding, environmental harms, and disease. The exact scope of the police-power exception is a matter of long-standing controversy, but at the very least it permits regulations that protect people against severe dangers, such as public-health sanitation requirements, building-code regulations to prevent the spread of fire, and the disposal of toxic waste and other industrial pollution. Few exclusionary-zoning restrictions fit within any plausible view of the police-power exception. Their main effect is to exclude low-income people, not protect against environmental or health threats.For those who reject originalist arguments, the main alternative framework of living constitutionalism, championed by many progressives, may be more persuasive. Living constitutionalism is a broad tent of theories about how to interpret the Constitution, which permits change over time. We argue at length elsewhere that multiple versions of the theory support striking down exclusionary zoning. Here we focus on the representation-reinforcement theory.      In Democracy and Distrust, the classic defense of representation-reinforcement theory, John Hart Ely argued that judicial review was not a counterweight to democracy, but rather a crucial facilitator of it. For democracy to prosper, voting rights and freedom of speech must be protected. The problem is that incumbent politicians and their constituents, seeking to maintain their power, would legislate to prevent political competition. Because these threats to democracy are produced by democracy, the solution must lie outside it, namely judicial review.Exclusionary zoning is a perfect example of Ely’s fear of the “ins choking off the channels of political change to ensure that they will stay in and the outs will stay out.” In this case, the “ins” are a community’s current residents, and the “outs” are potential residents. To protect their home values and other perceived interests, residents vote for politicians who will work to prevent construction that would entice newcomers. The latter have no opportunity to participate in the process. Some evidence suggests that NIMBY (“not in my backyard”) resistance to housing construction is caused by ignorance of housing economics, rather than by self-interest. Either way, insiders block outsiders.The standard solution to a lack of representation is simple: grant representation. But it is neither reasonable nor feasible for outsiders to have representation in a local government where they do not and may never live. The question is how to find another way to provide representation reinforcement for potential residents.      Here, judicial review can give voice to voiceless outsiders by providing them an opportunity to acquire the housing they need to move in, an idea Ely partly anticipated when he endorsed judicial protection for a “right to relocate.” The takings clause is the best option for this, given that it is the constitutional provision that protects private property from uncompensated government interference. And it is thus best fitted to the problem of exclusionary zoning, which limits the use of property.Ely also worried that certain groups, especially racial minorities, were subject to prejudice and hostility by the majority and would systematically be on the losing end of political decisions. The racist and classist history of zoning provides further justification for using judicial review to curb the practice, especially because the disproportionate impact on racial minorities persists to this day.      The Supreme Court has multiple plausible pathways to using the takings clause to restrict exclusionary zoning. Currently, zoning restrictions are analyzed under a nebulous three-factor balancing test first established in the 1978 Penn Central decision, which requires courts to consider the “economic impact of the regulation on the claimant,” the “extent to which the regulation has interfered with distinct investment-backed expectations,” and the “character of the government action.” In practice, this much-criticized test is usually applied in a highly deferential way.The best and simplest alternative to this framework would be for the Supreme Court to rule that exclusionary zoning is a “per se” (which is to say, automatic) taking, thus removing the need to consider the Penn Central factors. That would restore the original meaning, enforce the requirements of major living-Constitution theories, and minimize uncertainty. Alternatively, the Court could instead apply the Penn Central standards in a less deferential way.The Court could make exclusionary zoning a per se taking or ratchet up scrutiny under Penn Central without categorically overruling Euclid. For complex historical reasons, Euclid never directly addressed the takings clause. Technically, it upheld exclusionary zoning only against challenges under the due-process clause of the Fourteenth Amendment. The Court could simply confine Euclid to due-process clause cases, while making it clear that different standards apply to takings clause challenges.If all or even a large proportion of exclusionary zoning gets invalidated under the takings clause, the effect could be very great. If courts hold that a regulation is a taking, the government must pay compensation. Local governments could not afford to pay compensation to the many thousands of property owners whose rights are restricted by exclusionary zoning. They would likely be forced to repeal or severely constrain most exclusionary-zoning rules.[Jerusalem Demsas: The only force stronger than polarization? Rising home prices]YIMBY (“yes in my backyard”) zoning-reform advocates have won important legislative successes, but those victories are still confined to a minority of jurisdictions. By contrast, a Supreme Court ruling would apply to the entire nation. To be sure, local governments are experts at evading restrictions on their authority. But even somewhat imperfect enforcement of constitutional constraints on exclusionary zoning could have a significant impact by eliminating the most sweeping and effective exclusionary policies, and the most obvious ways to circumvent restrictions. If the judiciary effectively addressed the most blatant forms of exclusionary zoning, advocates could focus on the next frontier of zoning issues.In addition, stronger judicial enforcement of the takings clause could curb the use of state constitutional protections for local government autonomy to stymie zoning reform. The recent dubious California court decision striking down S.B. 9—a significant law limiting single-family zoning—is a notable example.Historically, successful constitutional-reform movements have combined legal and political action, and have not relied on one to the exclusion of the other. That was true for the civil-rights movement, the women’s-rights movement, advocates of same-sex marriage, gun-rights advocates, and others. The cross-ideological YIMBY movement should do the same.

America is suffering from a severe housing shortage. A crucial tool may lie in the Constitution.

America is suffering from a severe housing shortage, and one of the main culprits is exclusionary zoning: regulations that restrict the amount and type of housing that property owners are allowed to construct on their land. Exclusionary zoning slows economic growth, severely limits economic mobility, and imposes burdens that disproportionately fall on racial minorities.

No one simple solution to this problem exists. But a crucial tool may lie in the Constitution: the takings clause of the Fifth Amendment. The clause requires that, when the government takes “private property,” it must pay “just compensation” (usually the fair market value of the property rights taken). As we argue in a forthcoming Texas Law Review article, because exclusionary zoning severely restricts property owners’ right to use their land, we believe that it qualifies as such a taking, and is therefore unconstitutional unless the government pays compensation. Consistent enforcement of this interpretation would severely constrain exclusionary zoning, limiting it to cases where policy makers believe the benefits are worth the costs of paying compensation—and where they have the resources to do so.

Just as there is substantial cross-ideological agreement on the policy aspects of zoning reform, there can be similar broad agreement on the constitutional dimension of this issue. One of us, Ilya Somin, is a libertarian sympathetic to originalism. The other, Joshua Braver, is a progressive living constitutionalist. We differ on many things, but agree here.

The most significant type of exclusionary-zoning restriction is single-family-home zoning, which restricts housing construction in an area to homes that house only one family. Some 70 percent of all land zoned for residential use in the United States is limited to single-family residences only. Other types of exclusionary-zoning restrictions in many areas include minimum lot sizes, parking mandates, height restrictions, and more.

[M. Nolan Gray: Cancel zoning]

Exclusionary zoning severely reduces the housing supply in many jurisdictions, thereby preventing people from moving to areas where they could find better jobs and educational opportunities. It also increases homelessness by pricing poor residents out of the housing market. Exclusionary zoning causes enormous harm.

In an important recent study, the economists Gilles Duranton and Diego Puga found that abolition of zoning restrictions in seven major urban areas would increase America’s GDP by almost 8 percent. That’s because zoning blocks many people from moving to areas where they would be more productive. Even many current homeowners in severely restricted areas stand to benefit from zoning reform. They can gain from the resulting growth and innovation, and from lower housing costs for their children, among other things. For these and other reasons, curbing exclusionary zoning unites progressives, such as the members of President Joe Biden’s Council of Economic Advisers and the former Obama CEA chair Jason Furman, with libertarian-leaning free marketeers like Edward Glaeser of Harvard and Bryan Caplan of George Mason University.

Exclusionary zoning also has a horrible history of racism and classism. In Buchanan v. Warley (1917), the Supreme Court ruled that explicitly zoning neighborhoods by race was unconstitutional. But as scholars such as Richard Rothstein and Jessica Trounstine have documented, many jurisdictions got around the decision by enacting facially neutral laws that effectively excluded poor minorities by making it impossible for them to afford housing in the area. Many jurisdictions similarly priced out white poor people as well.

In 1926, the Supreme Court upheld such practices in Village of Euclid v. Ambler Realty Company, despite the district court’s warning that doing so would empower local governments “to classify the population and segregate them according to their income or situation in life.” Judge David C. Westenhaver of the Ohio District Court also presciently warned that the decision would result in racial segregation. Euclid was a terrible mistake, one the Supreme Court should fix.

And it can do so: When the Bill of Rights was enacted, in 1791, the right of private property was generally understood to include a right not just to exclude, but also to determine the use of that property. William Blackstone, the great British jurist whose Commentaries on the Laws of England enormously influenced the founding generation, famously wrote that “the third absolute right, inherent in every Englishman, is that of property: which consists in the free use, enjoyment, and disposal of all his acquisitions” (emphasis added). Use undoubtedly included building a house on one’s own property. Blackstone’s formulation was echoed by many of the American Founders, including—most notably—James Madison, the principal author of the takings clause. At the time of the founding, like today, housing was one of the most common uses of land.

Some originalists argue that the Bill of Rights, when applied to state and local governments, should be interpreted as understood not in 1791, but in 1868, when the ratification of the Fourteenth Amendment extended the limitations of the Bill of Rights to the states. In the 1868 understanding, the takings clause protected the owner’s right to use his property at his own discretion even more clearly than in 1791. In his influential 1868 treatise on constitutional law, Michigan Supreme Court Justice Thomas Cooley wrote that “any injury to the property of an individual which deprives the owner of the ordinary use of it is equivalent to a taking, and entitles him to compensation.” Prominent federal- and state-court takings decisions around the same time also emphasized the centrality of the right to use, including the Supreme Court’s famous 1871 decision in Pumpelly v. Green Bay Company. All significant forms of exclusionary zoning constrain the right to use, and therefore at least presumptively violate the takings clause.

Not every restriction on an owner’s right to use qualifies as a taking under the original meaning. Regulations that fit within the so-called police-power exception were not considered takings. Although the police-power exception has never been precisely defined, it generally applies to regulations that protect against significant threats to health and safety, such as fire, flooding, environmental harms, and disease. The exact scope of the police-power exception is a matter of long-standing controversy, but at the very least it permits regulations that protect people against severe dangers, such as public-health sanitation requirements, building-code regulations to prevent the spread of fire, and the disposal of toxic waste and other industrial pollution. Few exclusionary-zoning restrictions fit within any plausible view of the police-power exception. Their main effect is to exclude low-income people, not protect against environmental or health threats.

For those who reject originalist arguments, the main alternative framework of living constitutionalism, championed by many progressives, may be more persuasive. Living constitutionalism is a broad tent of theories about how to interpret the Constitution, which permits change over time. We argue at length elsewhere that multiple versions of the theory support striking down exclusionary zoning. Here we focus on the representation-reinforcement theory.      

In Democracy and Distrust, the classic defense of representation-reinforcement theory, John Hart Ely argued that judicial review was not a counterweight to democracy, but rather a crucial facilitator of it. For democracy to prosper, voting rights and freedom of speech must be protected. The problem is that incumbent politicians and their constituents, seeking to maintain their power, would legislate to prevent political competition. Because these threats to democracy are produced by democracy, the solution must lie outside it, namely judicial review.

Exclusionary zoning is a perfect example of Ely’s fear of the “ins choking off the channels of political change to ensure that they will stay in and the outs will stay out.” In this case, the “ins” are a community’s current residents, and the “outs” are potential residents. To protect their home values and other perceived interests, residents vote for politicians who will work to prevent construction that would entice newcomers. The latter have no opportunity to participate in the process. Some evidence suggests that NIMBY (“not in my backyard”) resistance to housing construction is caused by ignorance of housing economics, rather than by self-interest. Either way, insiders block outsiders.

The standard solution to a lack of representation is simple: grant representation. But it is neither reasonable nor feasible for outsiders to have representation in a local government where they do not and may never live. The question is how to find another way to provide representation reinforcement for potential residents.      

Here, judicial review can give voice to voiceless outsiders by providing them an opportunity to acquire the housing they need to move in, an idea Ely partly anticipated when he endorsed judicial protection for a “right to relocate.” The takings clause is the best option for this, given that it is the constitutional provision that protects private property from uncompensated government interference. And it is thus best fitted to the problem of exclusionary zoning, which limits the use of property.

Ely also worried that certain groups, especially racial minorities, were subject to prejudice and hostility by the majority and would systematically be on the losing end of political decisions. The racist and classist history of zoning provides further justification for using judicial review to curb the practice, especially because the disproportionate impact on racial minorities persists to this day.      

The Supreme Court has multiple plausible pathways to using the takings clause to restrict exclusionary zoning. Currently, zoning restrictions are analyzed under a nebulous three-factor balancing test first established in the 1978 Penn Central decision, which requires courts to consider the “economic impact of the regulation on the claimant,” the “extent to which the regulation has interfered with distinct investment-backed expectations,” and the “character of the government action.” In practice, this much-criticized test is usually applied in a highly deferential way.

The best and simplest alternative to this framework would be for the Supreme Court to rule that exclusionary zoning is a “per se” (which is to say, automatic) taking, thus removing the need to consider the Penn Central factors. That would restore the original meaning, enforce the requirements of major living-Constitution theories, and minimize uncertainty. Alternatively, the Court could instead apply the Penn Central standards in a less deferential way.

The Court could make exclusionary zoning a per se taking or ratchet up scrutiny under Penn Central without categorically overruling Euclid. For complex historical reasons, Euclid never directly addressed the takings clause. Technically, it upheld exclusionary zoning only against challenges under the due-process clause of the Fourteenth Amendment. The Court could simply confine Euclid to due-process clause cases, while making it clear that different standards apply to takings clause challenges.

If all or even a large proportion of exclusionary zoning gets invalidated under the takings clause, the effect could be very great. If courts hold that a regulation is a taking, the government must pay compensation. Local governments could not afford to pay compensation to the many thousands of property owners whose rights are restricted by exclusionary zoning. They would likely be forced to repeal or severely constrain most exclusionary-zoning rules.

[Jerusalem Demsas: The only force stronger than polarization? Rising home prices]

YIMBY (“yes in my backyard”) zoning-reform advocates have won important legislative successes, but those victories are still confined to a minority of jurisdictions. By contrast, a Supreme Court ruling would apply to the entire nation. To be sure, local governments are experts at evading restrictions on their authority. But even somewhat imperfect enforcement of constitutional constraints on exclusionary zoning could have a significant impact by eliminating the most sweeping and effective exclusionary policies, and the most obvious ways to circumvent restrictions. If the judiciary effectively addressed the most blatant forms of exclusionary zoning, advocates could focus on the next frontier of zoning issues.

In addition, stronger judicial enforcement of the takings clause could curb the use of state constitutional protections for local government autonomy to stymie zoning reform. The recent dubious California court decision striking down S.B. 9—a significant law limiting single-family zoning—is a notable example.

Historically, successful constitutional-reform movements have combined legal and political action, and have not relied on one to the exclusion of the other. That was true for the civil-rights movement, the women’s-rights movement, advocates of same-sex marriage, gun-rights advocates, and others. The cross-ideological YIMBY movement should do the same.

Read the full story here.
Photos courtesy of

Ignorance may be bliss, but knowledge is power

Cinema Verde provides environmental education to the public to help ensure that students, their parents, our political leaders and the titans of industry can learn about the problems we are facing so we can all work together to solve these problems. We all want our children to have the best possible future and to be able to enjoy happy, healthy lives. Students in Florida - and everywhere - have a resource to learn essential information about the environment and the challenges we face. 

The Florida Department of Education has agreed to suppress knowledge about environmental issues that are visibly threatening our future - essentially disabling our children from solving the problems that our generation and our parents’ generation have created. What parent would want their children to perish in fires like those in Maui and California or floods such as those in Maine and Vermont? When we send our children to school, we want to educate them so they can lead better lives - we are arming them with knowledge to build a safe and prosperous future for themselves and the world. What value is there in providing them with false information that will prevent them from that brighter future? Fossil fuel companies profit from poisoning our planet and they literally pay some of our government leaders to keep their profits flowing. Cinema Verde provides environmental education to the public to help ensure that students, their parents, our political leaders and the titans of industry can learn about the problems we are facing so we can all work together to solve these problems. We all want our children to have the best possible future and to be able to enjoy happy, healthy lives. Students in Florida - and everywhere - have a resource to learn essential information about the environment and the challenges we face. Cinema Verde offers a discount program for professors and students to access our films via our website at www.CinemaVerde.org. [More info: Discount for Professors and Students] Or anyone with a Roku tv or roku device can access our films for free. The films are organized in both places by category - you can search for water films or films on Florida, etc., to see what you want. https://www.cinemaverde.org/roku We gather articles from reputable sources around the world to provide environmental news on our GoGreenNation environmental news page: https://www.cinemaverde.org/news We’re not like Nazi’s, as the propaganda being fed to our children under the guise and sanction of education in Florida suggests. We at Cinema Verde are dedicated to helping and protecting our children and all children - even those of fossil fuel company executives and sold-out politicians who continue to spew lies - they’re trading our lives to fill their pockets with cash. We don’t have to allow this. Knowledge is power. Tune in to Cinema Verde - we are powering the planet for a successful future. – By Trish Riley, Director of Cinema Verde and award-winning investigative environmental journalist and author.

A war of words on CA ballot props

It’s one of the battles within California’s ballot measure wars: The wording that voters see about the propositions.  Monday marked the end of the public inspection period for the state’s official Voter Guide, so there was a flurry of activity. The Howard Jarvis Taxpayers Association was waiting to hear Monday night what a state appeals […]

Voters fill out their ballots at a polling place inside Assumption Church in Los Angeles on March 3, 2020. Photo by Kyle Grillot, Reuters It’s one of the battles within California’s ballot measure wars: The wording that voters see about the propositions.  Monday marked the end of the public inspection period for the state’s official Voter Guide, so there was a flurry of activity. The Howard Jarvis Taxpayers Association was waiting to hear Monday night what a state appeals court decided on a Sacramento County judge’s ruling that the ballot label for Proposition 5 needed to be rewritten. Critics have long complained that the state’s elected attorney general — they’ve all been Democrats since 1999 — skews the label, title and summary of ballot measures to match their political preferences.  The taxpayers association argued that the Prop. 5 label should say that it would lower the majority required to approve local borrowing measures from two-thirds to 55%. The original label — a condensed version of the title and summary — only included the 55% figure, so voters might believe that the threshold is being raised from a simple majority, the taxpayer group says. The ruling last week, which the attorney general’s office appealed, found that the label “fails to inform” voters the main purpose of Prop. 5, and that without “additional clarifying language,” the label could mislead voters. (Labels are allowed to run 75 words long and Prop. 5’s label is 65 words.) Laura Dougherty, the association’s director of legal affairs, said in an email to CalMatters that the attorney general “has a duty to inform the public of the chief points and purposes of every measure” and that “there are plenty of words left for the printer to add the information.” In his appeal, Attorney General Rob Bonta said the office is afforded “substantial deference” in determining ballot labels. Not only is Prop. 5’s label accurate, Bonta argued, but also that the court “seemingly invented a new” standard of review that granted his ballot materials less consideration “if he does not use all available words.” Rent control: It’s not just the title and summary: Supporters and opponents can also go to court about the official ballot arguments. The same judge on Monday found that four of the six statements made by the California Apartment Association about Prop. 33, a rent-control measure that the association opposes, must be deleted or amended. The court order called for language that hedges the association’s claims: For example, its argument must say Prop. 33 would “weaken,” not “repeal” renter protections, and “undermines,” not “eliminates” a statewide rent control law. School bond: There’s another battle brewing, this one on Prop. 2, which would let the state borrow $10 billion to fix and build schools and community colleges. The state Republican Party is weighing whether to endorse it, and a recommendation for “yes” from the party’s 14-member Initiatives Committee is drawing fire from California College Republicans and some Republican legislators.  The college group says Prop. 2 violates the party platform and also points out that the state party had a neutral position on Prop. 1, Gov. Gavin Newsom’s mental health measure on the March ballot that included $6.4 billion in bonds — and that barely passed. (The state Democratic Party is supporting Prop. 2.)  GOP delegates can reject the committee’s recommendation with a two-thirds majority and have until Aug. 28 to vote. Ellie Hockenbury, California GOP spokesperson: “The CAGOP’s ballot initiative endorsement process is still underway, and we have not yet taken a position on Proposition 2. The party greatly respects our delegates and values their opinion as part of that process.” November election: Keep up with CalMatters coverage by signing up for 2024 election emails. Check out our Voter Guide, including updates and videos on the 10 propositions and a FAQ on how to vote. More honors: Sisi Wei, now chief impact officer at CalMatters, won the leadership in diversity and solidarity award from the Asian American Journalists Association for her work as editor in chief of The Markup, which joined CalMatters earlier this year. Speaking of the AAJA, it partnered with CalMatters for the second year of JCal, a summer training program for high school journalists. Read more on both from our engagement team. CalMatters covers the Capitol: We have guides and stories to keep track of bills and your lawmakers; find out how well legislators are representing you; explore the Legislature’s record diversity; and to make your voice heard. Other Stories You Should Know Time is short on insurance fix State Insurance Commissioner Ricardo Lara speaks during a press conference with labor leaders and advocates in Commerce on Sept. 26, 2022. Photo by Alisha Jucevic for CalMatters From CalMatters economy reporter Levi Sumagaysay: California Insurance Commissioner Ricardo Lara bypassed the Legislature and announced changes that could mean insurance companies’ requests to raise premiums would get approved more quickly.  As the state scrambles to deal with problems with property insurance availability and affordability, a planned trailer bill by Gov. Newsom proposed speeding up insurance rate reviews to get insurance companies to start or resume writing more policies here. (Trailer bills are attached to the state budget, and sometimes change policy with minimal public discussion.)  But apparently even this shortcut was not fast enough: On Friday, the Insurance Department and the governor’s office said they needed to act immediately, so Lara issued a bulletin that does the same thing as the trailer bill. “We do not have the luxury of time,” Lara said in a press release. The Legislature actually took no action on the trailer bill, according to two sources familiar with the matter. They said the proposal was more about policy and not about the budget, so lawmakers — who are having to make difficult choices as they deal with a multibillion-dollar deficit — didn’t even consider it. Democratic Senate Pro Tem Mike McGuire of Santa Rosa did not seem to mind that Lara issued a bulletin instead. “The importance is intensifying as wildfires continue to take lives, destroy homes, and level communities,” he said in a statement. The changes Lara announced in the bulletin establishes a tighter timeline for rate reviews and are one part of his broader plan to try to fix the state’s insurance woes. The Insurance Department must respond within 60 days of a rate review, with room for two 30-day extensions, once its new rate-reconciliation tool that will help with the process is up and running. This is expected to be in January, according to department spokesperson Michael Soller. Insurance companies have complained about rate reviews taking too long, so some representatives of the insurance industry have said the changes are necessary.  But Consumer Watchdog, an advocacy group that often challenges rate reviews, is looking into the commissioner’s authority to make such changes. Carmen Balber, the group’s executive director, told CalMatters the stricter timelines for rate reviews might “limit consumers’ voice in oversight.” Speaking of insurance: Rising insurance costs don’t just impact single-family homeowners. Levi dives into how insurance companies have nearly stopped writing policies for apartment and commercial properties, too. And landlords could pass higher insurance premiums onto tenants, further worsening the state’s housing crunch. Uwe Karbenk, a landlord who co-owns a building in San Bernardino, said soaring premiums are especially hard for mom-and-pop landlords. Landlords are already limited by state laws over how much they’re allowed to raise rent each year, and another rent-control measure is on the Nov. 5 ballot. To be a landlord in the state is like “death by a thousand cuts,” said Karbenk. Read more about the impact of rising insurance costs in Levi’s story. Should CA schools build housing? Carolina Sanchez Garcia cooks with her daughter, Berthalinda Hernandez, 6, at their home in San Diego on Aug. 7, 2024. Photo by Zoë Meyers for CalMatters To address the state’s high cost of living and looming teacher shortage, California’s schools chief Tony Thurmond laid out an ambitious plan in July to develop more housing for teachers using land owned by school districts.  While some teachers have benefited greatly from similar housing projects, some superintendents remain wary, writes CalMatters K-12 education reporter Carolyn Jones. Thurmond’s plan includes financial incentives for districts that pass bonds to build staff housing. But many districts can’t even pass bonds to repair existing school buildings. Some superintendents also say they’re already spread too thin — to expect them to undertake complex real estate projects is a tall ask.  Mendocino County Superintendent Nicole Glentzer: “When you’re the superintendent and the principal and head of maintenance and you’re teaching Spanish, how are you supposed to find the bandwidth for this? I have a degree in education. I never took a real estate course.” But supporters of the plan point to teachers such as Carolina Sanchez Garcia, a San Diego preschool teacher. For more than a decade, she said she commuted from Tijuana, waking up at 2 a.m. to get to work on time. After landing a three-bedroom apartment through San Diego Unified, it now takes her 15 minutes to get to work. She pays $1,300 a month in a city where the median rent is $3,156 a month. Garcia: “It’s changed my life. … It’s made me a better mother and a better teacher. Now, I start my day feeling positive and energized.” Learn more about affordable housing for teachers in Carolyn’s story. California Voices CalMatters columnist Dan Walters: Gov. Newsom is quick to blame local governments for not doing enough to reduce homelessness, but experts and local officials say withholding state funds is the biggest impediment. California Voices intern Kate McQuarrie: Seven years after the #MeToo movement galvanized women in the state Legislature, accusations of sexual assault within the San Francisco Democratic Party underscore how prevalent sexual misconduct remains in California politics. Other things worth your time: Some stories may require a subscription to read. CA Legislature passes bills to curb retail theft // Los Angeles TimesDemocrats strip party switcher Alvarado-Gil of leadership, committee posts // KCRA Sen. Atkins, 2026 candidate for governor, missed retail theft bill votes // The Sacramento Bee Environmental justice cause is drawing Harris both cheers and attacks // Politico New CA laws take effect as the school year begins // EdSource Widely felt 4.4 earthquake rattles Los Angeles // Los Angeles Times CA’s oldest family-owned rice farm is closing // San Francisco Chronicle Fentanyl is getting weaker, making users more desperate // The San Francisco Standard Where LA stands on key transit projects for 2028 Olympics LAist Golden Gate Bridge protesters surrender to face controversial charges // KQED

How the Olympic Village Evolved From Makeshift Cabins to a City Within a City

The athletes' accommodations have come a long way in the last 100 years, expanding into modern global hubs

The Smithsonian’s National Museum of American History has in its collection an object that provides entry into the very first Olympic Village: 1924 U.S. boxing team assistant manager Ben Levine’s official Olympic ID. The simple paper badge would have gotten Levine into his Olympic accommodations, a complex organized and specially constructed by the host city “complete with running water, a post office and hairdresser,” according to the museum’s description. Prior to the 1924 Summer Olympics in Paris, where a participant slept, what they ate and how they got to the site fell either on their team’s shoulders or their own. As such, players were scattered about the city with no central gathering place outside of competition. They stayed in hotels, rooming houses or with host families, and ate, trained and hung out on their own, making transportation a logistical nightmare. For an event designed to bring the entire world together for a few weeks in the name of international sportsmanship, the disparate nature of the typical athlete’s experience was antithetical to the spirit of the Games. At least, that’s what Pierre de Coubertin thought. A co-founder of the International Olympic Committee (IOC), Coubertin is widely considered the father of the modern Games thanks to his role in bringing to life the 1896 Summer Olympics in Athens and, in doing so, creating the blueprint for all future Olympics as multinational, multi-sport exhibitions. The French aristocrat was bullish about exercise, believing it was integral to any good education and that playing organized sports imbued participants with moral fortitude. He also believed that sports had the power to promote peace across borders, seeing friendly competition as a means for important cultural exchange and understanding. The 1924 Paris Olympics were Coubertin’s final Games before retirement, his last shot at putting his international philosophy into action via thousands of athletes. That year, Coubertin’s IOC decreed via the General Technical Rules (now known as the Olympic Charter) that the Olympic organizing committee would be “required to provide the athletes with accommodation, bedding and food, at a fixed rate which shall be set beforehand per person and per day.” In response, Olympic organizers in Paris erected a series of makeshift wooden cabins with everything from sleeping quarters and mess halls to a currency exchange and dry-cleaner. It wasn’t much to look at, but with three beds to a room and shared dining areas offering three meals each day, it certainly brought the athletes closer together. Coubertin’s vision had come to fruition. Now, 100 years later, the village comes full circle with the 2024 Olympics, once again in Paris. The concept of the village has grown to meet current ideals. “An Olympic Village needs to provide the necessary accommodation for athletes and support teams during the games, needs to be flexible to anticipate the various cultural and religious needs and customs of the Olympic guests, and support all the needs of accommodating so many people,” says Steve Wallis, associate director of dRMM Architects, one of the London firms behind the Olympic Village for the 2012 Summer Games. “Individually, the buildings or plots should have their own identities.”Setting the standard The 1932 Olympic Village under construction in Los Angeles, California UPI / Bettmann Archive / Getty Images As the Olympics evolved, so did the Olympic Village. The 1932 Los Angeles Games upped the ante, featuring modular bungalows for up to 2,000 athletes along with upgraded amenities like medical services, an open-air amphitheater and an array of flags at the entrance setting the tone for the global mini-city. “Here athletes from the four quarters of the globe, with foreign customs, strange languages and different ideas, lived, associated and fraternized for the period of the Games,” wrote then-American Olympic Association president Avery Brundage in 1932’s American Olympic Committee report. “A large share of the credit for broken records can be ascribed to the superior arrangements for the comfort of the athletes.” Every Summer Olympics from that year forward—with the exception of the 1948 London Games due to war-related budget constraints—featured a bigger and more diverse Olympic Village, each continuing to encourage cross-cultural mingling among participants. While the original villages were limited to male Olympians, women joined the fold in 1956—though they’d been competing since 1900—when Melbourne organizers incorporated a separate women’s quarters into their village design. Men weren’t allowed inside this designated area, but dining halls and other shared spaces became co-ed. By the 1984 Los Angeles Games, built-in gender divides had dissolved, and athletes were instead housed by team. Eventually, the Olympics burst onto the television screens that began proliferating in American living rooms, and the villages also leaned into technology. The 1960 Rome Olympics saw a sprawling complex with restaurants, shops and a movie theater. The 1964 Tokyo Games further embraced innovation, incorporating more efficiently constructed prefabricated housing units in addition to Rome’s bells and whistles. “The Olympic Village afforded the athletes fine accommodations. The village itself was complete in every detail with a bank, post office, stores, entertainment facilities and fine dining halls,” wrote Kenneth L. Wilson, president of the United States Olympic Committee from 1953 to 1965, in the U.S. Olympic Committee’s 1960 report. “If there was any criticism to be given, it was that the meals were too good and too tempting for athletes who were on a training diet.” But later, dark moments would cloud the village and Games. During the 1972 Munich Olympics, eight members of the Palestinian militant organization Black September breached the Olympic village five years after the Six-Day War. The group captured and killed two members of the Israeli Olympic team and took nine others hostage, eventually killing them too. Many blamed the Olympic Village’s lax security for the massacre, and subsequent host cities tightened up their athlete access and internal security force, forever altering the spirit of the villages. “Yugoslav soldiers, many armed with Kalashnikov sub-machine guns and some flanked by guard dogs, patrolled the perimeter of Mojmilo, the main Olympic Village, the temporary home for most of the 1,591 athletes representing 49 nations in the 1984 Winter Games,” reads the introduction of the U.S. Olympic Committee’s report from that year. “Memories of 1972, when Palestinian terrorists infiltrated the athletes’ quarters in Munich and murdered 11 Israelis, made security a major Olympic concern in Sarajevo. Electronic detectors monitored every item brought into the village, and electrified fences, seven feet high, discouraged intruders.”Life beyond the torch A satellite image of the Olympic Village in London, collected on July 23, 2012 DigitalGlobe via Getty Images While the early constructions were purposefully disposable, later host countries began building their villages with an eye toward use well after the closing ceremony. Modern Olympic Villages “function for the duration of the games, but also have a life beyond this,” Wallis says. The post-Cold War era saw a renewed focus on environmental responsibility. In 1992, the Barcelona Olympics utilized pre-existing structures and emphasized public transportation access, converting its seafront Olympic Village’s dining hall into a shopping mall, while the training center became a multi-use arena. Subsequent Games followed suit, with a focus on making use of the infrastructure beyond the events, as in Sydney in 2000, where its Olympic Village was turned into housing complete with schools and child care facilities for more than 5,000 residents, and Beijing in 2008, where much of the village became public parkland and memorial spaces. “The lessons learned from the London Olympics show that consideration of the legacy of the village is essential,” says Wallis. According to Wallis, 16 different architectural practices came together to create that year’s Olympic Village, which spanned 11 plots of land and 67 different buildings. A master-plan design code ensured that each plot’s firm stayed within the aesthetic bounds of the project while also leaving its own mark. From the start, the architects behind the London Village knew they wanted to create something that not only met the needs of the Olympics but also could later seamlessly integrate itself into London’s greater urban fabric. After the athletes packed up and went home, what remained was a brand-new district—one that even got its own name. “East Village, as the London Olympic Village is now known, has been very successfully transformed into a high-quality neighborhood,” Wallis says. “The high-density housing blocks are well balanced with landscaped public realm and active pedestrianized boulevards that buzz with commercial uses—it’s a wonderful representation of an English mews street writ large for the 21st century.”Building goodwill from the inside out A view of the Olympic Village dining hall ahead of the Paris 2024 Olympic Games, on July 23, 2024 Kevin Voigt / GettyImages While the villages’ original function was to house athletes and create a self-sustaining hub where residents can access everything they need without ever leaving the complex, today’s Olympic Villages strike more of a balance between keeping competitors there and showing them everything the host city has to offer. As in London, the 2024 Paris Olympic Village is also redefining its city’s layout. Stashed right on the Seine River, the village was designed to blend into the surrounding area, creating a new public space for residents and visitors alike. The emphasis on green spaces, pedestrian-friendly pathways and waterfront access aims to enhance the quality of life not just for the Olympians, but also for the local community. Of course, this same ethos didn’t exactly ring true in Tokyo, where the 2020 Games were delayed to 2021 because of the Covid-19 pandemic, and Olympic Village harmony took a back seat to limiting the spread of the virus. Coming and going in tightly orchestrated shifts, Tokyo athletes had to adhere to a strict schedule, and socializing with other teams—both inside and outside the village—was kept to a minimum. “The Paris Village feels more energetic and packed than Tokyo. In Tokyo, because of Covid, we had a pretty limited window of time before and after our event where we were allowed to be out there, so it was never at capacity,” says current USA Skateboarding women’s team head coach Alexis Sablone, who also competed at the Tokyo Games as a member of Team USA. “Here in Paris, we can also actually leave, so every night the bars and restaurants surrounding the village feel full—it’s definitely nice to see how that energy spills out.” The state of the modern-day Olympic Village, it seems, is mutable. It’s designed with the efficiency and security needed to keep athletes happy and healthy inside, while simultaneously porous enough to soak up the host country’s essence. “It’s so nice to get to spend time outside and experience the city,” adds Sablone. “I wish we had been able to do that in Tokyo, but obviously, it was a very different time, and I’m just glad we got to go to Tokyo at all.” Get the latest on what's happening At the Smithsonian in your inbox.

What to watch with your kids: ‘Harold and the Purple Crayon’ and more

Common Sense Media also reviews “Saving Bikini Bottom: The Sandy Cheeks Movie,” “A Good Girl’s Guide to Murder” and “Batman: Caped Crusader.”

Harold and the Purple Crayon (PG)Age 8+Aged-up picture book adaptation includes peril and fight scenes.“Harold and the Purple Crayon” is based on the popular 1955 children’s book of the same name. While Harold is a young child in the book, the movie transforms him into an animated adult (Zachary Levi) who uses his magic crayon to transport himself and his pals Moose (Lil Rel Howery) and Porcupine (Tanya Reynolds) into the real world. There, he meets a widowed mom (Zooey Deschanel) and her still-grieving son (Benjamin Bottani). Although the Harold books were appropriate for toddlers and preschoolers, this adaptation has a fair bit of action and some potentially frightening moments. A child is taunted and hurt by bullies, Harold’s creations cause a fair bit of chaos and destruction, and there’s a climactic fight involving fire-breathing creatures. There are also a few jokey, suggestive comments that make it seem like Harold is romantically interested in another character — even though he has no such inclinations in his innocent, childlike state. The bullying scenes involve some harsh comments, but the movie also promotes creativity, courage and teamwork. (92 minutes)Saving Bikini Bottom: The Sandy Cheeks Movie (Unrated)Age 6+Female-led SpongeBob spinoff has slapstick action and mild peril.Coming from the SpongeBob SquarePants franchise, this hybrid of live action and animation shines the spotlight on the squirrel sidekick Sandy (voiced by Carolyn Lawrence). The violence is slapstick, the peril is not truly worrisome, and the villain Sue Nahmee (Wanda Sykes) and her minions are over-the-top silly. Still, be prepared for bizarre images of distorted bodies that may disturb small children. There’s a reference to a character’s flesh being sewn together (with an animated visual), and a human head bounces around and gets attached to nonhuman bodies. Expect some potty humor and use of “butt.” Sandy is a great role model who is passionate about her work as an environmental scientist, and teamwork also looms large as Sandy and SpongeBob (Tom Kenny) come to the aid of their friends. (86 minutes)A Good Girl’s Guide to Murder (TV-MA)Age 14+Intriguing teen mystery has drugs, violence and language.Based on the books by Holly Jackson, this mystery series stars Emma Myers as Pip, a girl who is motivated to solve the five-year-old murder of another teen in her small U.K. town. We see a bloody head wound, and one character threatens sexual assault. Drug use and dealing play a major role in this story, and characters are seen snorting ketamine at a wild party. Rohypnol use is another plot point, and underage characters drink alcohol frequently. Language includes “s---” and “f---.” Teens kiss and find romance. There’s some discussion of nudes, and a character finds condoms while snooping in another teen’s room. While there is definitely some edgy content, Pip (the titular “good girl”) is driven by a strong sense of justice and often learns from her mistakes. (Six episodes)Batman: Caped Crusader (TV-Y7)Age 9+Lots of action in stand-alone superhero stories; violence.This animated superhero series has a retro, film noir vibe and lots of cartoonish violence and action — gunfire, fistfighting and explosions. One character drowns in a suitcase, and another is fatally stabbed. Batman (expertly voiced by Hamish Linklater) breaks a villain’s hand. Language includes “damn,” “a--,” “load of bull,” “freaking” and “hell.” Older, comic-loving kids should enjoy this group of fresh, action-packed tales from the heart of Gotham City. (10 episodes)Available on Prime Video.Common Sense Media helps families make smart media choices. Go to commonsense.org for age-based and educational ratings and reviews for movies, games, apps, TV shows, websites and books.

Suggested Viewing

Join us to forge
a sustainable future

Our team is always growing.
Become a partner, volunteer, sponsor, or intern today.
Let us know how you would like to get involved!

CONTACT US

sign up for our mailing list to stay informed on the latest films and environmental headlines.

Subscribers receive a free day pass for streaming Cinema Verde.
Thank you! Your submission has been received!
Oops! Something went wrong while submitting the form.